Geert Lovink on Wed, 30 Jul 1997 18:55:36 +0200 (MET DST) |
[Date Prev] [Date Next] [Thread Prev] [Thread Next] [Date Index] [Thread Index]
<nettime> dx-lecture by Susan George: Economy and Ecology |
See also: http://www.documenta.de/workspace for an interview with Susan George. ECONOMY AND ECOLOGY WAYS OF LOOKING AT THE WORLD DOCUMENTA X: ONE HUNDRED DAYS, ONE HUNDRED GUESTS 15 JULY 1997 SUSAN GEORGE The Curator of Documenta X has asked a hundred people of different backgrounds to 'present their standpoint towards globalisation'. Artists express their reflections on society in highly symbolic and often prophetic ways. I'm not an artist and I want to take Catherine David's invitation to reflect on globalisation in a very literal and material sense. Aside from the language and medium of art, there are basically two dominant contemporary views of the world, the ecological and the economic. I will argue that these two worldviews are fundamentally incompatible and locked in warfare, whether or not this war has yet been recognised by most people. The outcome of this war will decide nothing less than the future of humanity and indeed whether or not humanity even has a future. This may sound apocalyptic, but I hope to show that the contradictions between economy and ecology are so deep that we ignore them at our peril. Economy and ecology share the same Greek root, oikos, which means the household, estate or domain. The eco-nomos is the set of rules and regulations for running the domain; while the eco-logos is the reason for it all, the underlying principle, the spirit; in the sense that Saint John affirms at the outset of his Gospel 'In the beginning was the Logos', usually translated as the Word. To me, the Logos necessarily includes humans and their natural surroundings; we are all part of the same physical reality, the same household or domain. Given the Greek root, you would think that the Logos is the greater of the two and should supersede the Nomos; that the spirit and underlying principle should override and define the rules and regulations; that an eco-Logos should be the guiding force behind the economy. And in fact, throughout history, social goals have always been put first and defined the nature of the economy, including some we now find repulsive, like economic systems based on slavery or human sacrifice. Today, however, for the first time, the economy, the forces of the globalised free market, are dictating the rules to society, shaping our relationships with each other and with the natural world. The eco-nomos, the globalised economy, the marketplace refuse to take second place to the Logos or to anything else. They have claimed leadership of the world. I said I would take the invitation to reflect on globalisation materially and literally. Nothing could be more literal and material than the state of the actual, physical globe. I won't spend time on a catalogue of environmental horrors and dangers: you surely do not need to be reminded of changing climate, disappearing ozone, razed forests, massive species extinctions, polluted air and water, disfigureed coastlines, desertified or asphalted land--the list goes on. But this is summer and much of Germany has already left or is about to leave on holiday, so I'd like to take an example of particular interest to Europe which is the source of European civilisation--the Mediterranean. Western art begins there with the Egyptians and the Greeks; the Mediterranean is the sea where history and culture began. How ought we to look at the Mediterranean today if we are objective and honest? The picture is pretty depressing. Here are some figures: along the 46.000 kilometres of Mediterranean coastline live 130 million permanent residents joined each year by at least 100 million tourists. This population produces an annual 500 million tons of raw sewage, piped, untreated, directly into the sea. Add to that annual total 60.000 tonnes of detergents, several thousand tonnes of heavy metals, huge quantities of nitrates from fertiliser run-offs and over 600.000 tonnes of petroleum. Mediterranean ports are rarely equipped for cleaning oil tanks so they are emptied at sea along with the rest of the rubbish. The predatory plant caulerpa taxifolia is colonising the sea floor and creating irreversible biological pollution; over-fishing and disease are destroying stocks of fish and other marine species. Dolphins are choking on plastics. Fishermen are killing off monk seals because they compete for the fish. The sea is not flushed because the waters of the Nile are now entirely used for irrigation, Gibraltar lets virtually nothing from the Atlantic past the pillars and the Black Sea is, if anything, more polluted than the Mediterranean itself. This is now the objective, physical state of the sea which has inspired poets and artists from Homer and Phidias onwards. No wonder the New Scientist entitled a recent article 'The Mediterranean: Dirty, Dangerous and Doomed?' That, anyway, is the ecological conclusion. But for the economy, as we now measure it, all these activities contributing to the destruction and the utter defilement of this sea are excellent news. Mass tourism contributes to GNP; production of chemicals, plastics and detergents provides employment; nitrates and irrigation help boost crop yields for farmers; petroleum keeps our industries ticking over. If you're still depressed by the state of the Med, you can go out to dinner at a nice fish restaurant, at least as long as supplies last. So never mind. Not to worry. A great deal of money is being made! It's not just the Mediterranean, of course, or just Western Europe. State socialism caused environmental devastation on an even greater scale. The centrally planned economies of Eastern Europe were and remain ecological disaster zones. In large measure they were simply imitating predatory Western productivist patterns that began with the Industrial Revolution, with even worse environmental results because citizens could not protest or organise against the destruction. The eco-nomos is today triumphant and is forcibly integrating the entire globe according to the rules of the marketplace and of neo-liberalism. This is precisely the meaning of 'globalisation'. Since the fall of the Berlin Wall, neo-liberal capitalism has had no serious rivals, privatisation is snowballing, global competition is advancing inexorably. Besides 'integration', 'privatisation', and 'competition', another big word in the globalisation vocabulary is 'deregulation'. Its ironic to hear neo-liberal economists talk about deregulation. They invariably mean that States should get rid of laws and regulations that protect their citizens and natural environments from external threats. In reality, plenty of rules are in place and more are being made every day: it's just that they all favour the needs of capital and transnational corporations, not the needs of people and society to reproduce themselves or the needs of the planet to restore itself. Deregulation in practice means that in the United States, the Republican majority in Congress is attempting to dismantle the Environmental Protection Agency. European welfare-state measures are under direct attack from the forces of globalisation. Employment comes a distant second to the goal of corporate competitivity. Companies are downsizing, shedding workers like trees shed leaves in the fall. In the South, the World Bank and the International Monetary Fund impose neo-liberal rules on poor and heavily indebted countries, orienting their economies towards export production, refusing them all possibility of protecting their infant industries and dictating their budgetary choices in every respect. An African participant in such negotiations reports that during a review of the health budget, the Minister announced that 14 new public health nurses would be recruited. The World Bank representative shot back, 'We told you you could only hire nine'. At the international level, the document establishing the World Trade Organisation, the successor to the GATT, is some 20.000 pages long. It describes in the smallest detail the rights of corporations to produce, buy, sell or invest across national boundaries. On the other hand, it contains no rules at all concerning any obligations of these same corporations to reduce waste, pollution and environmental destruction or to pay decent wages, give enough time off and provide safe working conditions. At the Rio Conference of 1992--whose fifth anniversary meeting recently ended in abject failure--the agenda was dominated by the World Business Council for Sustainable Development--a tragically ironic name, given that its membership includes some of the world's major corporate polluters and destroyers of the environment. The Business Council's great victory in Rio was to avoid all mention of regulation for transnational corporation activity. These companies are now officially assumed to be capable of self-regulation. The Rio Declaration recognises that 'States have the sovereign right to exploit their own resources': this means that corporations acting within the boundaries of those States and using their environments have the right to exploit those resources. All countries now compete to attract transnational investment which now stands above $3 trillion and has dramatically increased since the beginning of the decade. Countries which are least demanding with regard to social protection or environmental regulations, while offering docile, low paid and productive labour forces are most likely to win the prize of investment. The internal logic of the capitalist market is to expand until everything falls within its purview; until everything can be bought and sold, including people and nature. For the overwhelming majority of people in industrialised countries, basic human needs like food, clothing and shelter are already entirely dependent on money: no money means no food and no housing. As far as the market is concerned, people are not 'human beings' but 'labour'; they are counted more as costs than as assets. Nature is considered as 'real estate' or building sites, as a source of raw materials' and as a place to dump wastes. You may find all this painfully obvious and I apologise if I'm covering thoroughly familiar ground, but in my experience many people are still surprised or shocked by such statements. It would be far more surprising that capitalist producers behave any differently, particularly in a fully globalised market. Their imperative is to maintain and improve market share and profit in a highly competitive environment where no one is doing anyone any favours. In order to survive, even the largest companies must try to insure that someone else pays the bill for human and natural degradation and destruction. This is what economists call 'externalising the costs of production'. If the corporations had to pay these costs, they would have to charge more for their products, consumers would then consume less, economic activity would contract, firms would fail, greater unemployment would result--that, at least, is the theory. In a globalised system where everyone is at war with everyone else for a place in the sun and a share of the market, the logic of the eco-nomos is necessarily to keep labour costs low, to minimise ecological protection; to strip resources and dump wastes as cheaply as possible. Here are two simple examples concerning common, everyday products: Nike shoes left the United States in the 1980s and went to Korea. When Korean workers struck for higher wages, Nike moved to Indonesia. Wages there have now reached $2.50 a day, below the level needed for physiological reproduction. Indonesian workers struck for better pay in April of this year and, as one of the Nike managers said, 'There's concern that Indonesia could be pricing itself out of the market'. Nike is now moving part of its production to Vietnam. For an example closer to home, the world automobile industry now produces some 79 million cars a year, but can sell only 57 million. Shouldn't the market itself correct such a crazy and wasteful situation of oversupply? Theoretically, it should. But all car manufacturers are now racing each other to reduce labour costs. They are, however, investing in more expensive equipment to catch up with the best, like Toyota which can now build a luxury car with only 18 hours worth of labour content. Huge over-capacity results, so it becomes quite logical in these circumstances that Renault should shut down an almost brand-new plant at Vilvoorde in Belgium. Meanwhile, more unemployment and lower wages mean that fewer people can afford cars. The average American family used to need 18 weeks of wages to buy the average American car. Now it takes the same family 28 weeks to buy the same car.* Henry Ford knew you had to pay your workers enough so that they could buy the cars they made. No such logic operates at the global level. Perhaps we should rejoice from an ecological point of view that there may be fewer cars on the road--at least until China starts mass-production--but this is of small consolation to the hundreds of thousands of workers who have lost their jobs. The market can be formidably efficient and can do many things well. What it should not be expected or allowed to do is to make our social and environmental choices for us. Society has to define precisely the limits of those things the market should and should not do; society has to distinguish what should or should not be bought and sold; society has to determine who should pay the costs now externalised by producers. These are political questions in the deepest sense; questions of power relations. They are enormously difficult, perhaps impossible, to solve in a globalised world, at least until global crisis or global accident strikes. Most economists still claim that we should simply let the market get on with its business; that it is the best allocator of both material and human resources; that it will ultimately recognise and outlaw waste and scarcity by making them too costly. These theorists often point to the work of the great founder of liberalism, Adam Smith, who proclaimed that the pursuit of self-interest in the marketplace by millions of people would lead to unintended but generally benign social outcomes. The theorists today would add that the market can also lead to benign environmental outcomes if it is left to itself. Poor Adam Smith! He never thought of himself as an 'economist' but as a 'moral philosopher'. He saw man as a social being, possessed of what he called 'fellow feeling', deeply concerned with the good opinion of others. Thus in the competitive race, Smith said, a man will not 'jostle or throw down any of his competitors'. In a globalised world, on the contrary, everyone tries to jostle and throw down all competitors who might threaten market share and profits. Smith seems to have been wrong about human behaviour and social outcomes in a globalised and competitive world. I think it can be shown conclusively as well that the famous Invisible Hand and market self-regulation do not and cannot work in the case of ecological outcomes. In a competitive environment, each fisherman or logger has an interest in taking as many fish or trees as he can, right now. It is in each oil company's or chemical company's interest to clean its tanks or dispose of its wastes efficiently, in the Mediterranean if that's the cheapest solution. It is in each individual farmer's interest to apply fertiliser; never mind the run-offs. And so on. Let me take another example from the Mediterranean: I was on the Ionian coast of Turkey in April. The frenetic pace of hotel and high-rise apartment construction there vastly outstrips local capacity to keep the sea or the beaches clean because such undertakings are necessarily collective or cooperative, not individual ones. In such situations, the well-known paradox of the free rider immediately surfaces: anyone volunteering to undertake the clean-up is a fool, economically speaking, because he will pay all the costs, yet allow everyone else to reap the benefits. If no collective authority, stemming either from the local community, a business association or the State specifically decides to clean up after the mess of raw capitalist entrepreneurship, or forces the entrepreneurs to do so themselves, the environment necessarily suffers. When capital can cross borders at will and seek out new places to set up factories, strip resources, exploit cheap labour and dump wastes, it is naturally hostile to regulation. Let's assume that somehow nearly everyone recognises the need for regulation. Even then, to make the system work, all countries, rich and poor, and all corporations, would have to adopt the same standards at the same time. Otherwise, the countries or companies which were first to take the initiative and internalised ecological and human costs would be at an immediate economic disadvantage. They would lose investment and markets and would ultimately be ruined or left behind. Unfortunately the market recognises and responds only to short term interests. Natural space is nothing but a source of raw materials and a site for waste dumping. In the same way, the market functions within a framework of time which is completely antithetical to that of natural time. Production and reproduction are totally different processes and cannot be governed by the same measurements. Nature cannot be hurried. It requires rest and renewal. Its rhythms contrast sharply with the speed of the marketplace which is a creature of the eternal present, always focused on that imaginary point where supply intersects with demand and price is established. In the marketplace, the fast devour the slow. Market actors try their best to compress natural time. When they cannot simply eliminate human beings from the production process, manufacturers find ways to make the labour force move faster. Ever since the Industrial Revolution and Taylorism, a major source of friction between labour and management has been production speed-ups. The owners of one plant in Thailand put amphetamines in the drinking water; some of the workers later gave birth to deformed babies. The market wants plants to grow faster and animals to mature faster. No wonder we're losing bio-diversity and raising herds of mad cows. At a deeper level, the opposition between economic time and natural time is epistemological; a conflict between ways of seeing and explaining the world. The keywords here are reversible and irreversible. Since Adam Smith's time, standard neo-classical economics textbooks have treated economic processes as inherently reversible. The equations in these texts always assume that endless permutations are possible--permutations between land, labour and capital; rent, wages and profits and other supposedly independent variables. All of them are supposed to be capable of reverting to initial conditions. Marxist economists reason in exactly the same way. Unfortunately, nature simply doesn't function according to the laws of Newtonian mechanics. In fact, nearly all significant natural changes are permanent and irreversible. Once a tropical forest is cut down, experts say it would require a minimum of 400 years to reproduce it--and even then, one could not be sure of the result. A major debate in climatology today concerns the possibility that North Atlantic ocean currents are changing because of accelerated polar meltdowns due to global warming. One of the determinants of these currents, a tongue of ice called the Ogden feature, has failed in its pump-priming functions for three years running, an unprecedented occurrence. Oceanographers fear such changes in ocean currents will have a knock-on effect and weaken the Gulf Stream. Were that to happen, global warming would paradoxically cause Northern Europe to become much colder, like northern Canada which is at the same latitude. The phenomenon would be swift and irreversible--at least on any imaginable human time scale. Such a change of climate would clearly have incalculable economic effects, but neo-classical economics is not a predictive science and the market cannot possibly warn of impending ecological catastrophe until it is too late. This is nonetheless what we are inherently asking it to do. Market prices rarely even tell us about scarcity. Because so many players are competing for export revenues, market supply is plentiful so long as the resource lasts. Thus the market doesn't even tell us how much natural capital, like fish and forests, we have left. What's more, prices tell us nothing about the fragility of the natural systems we depend on. We have become accustomed to relying on 'market signals', or changes in prices, for virtually all our economic and political decisions. Thus we fail to recognise that in this crucial area of environmental decline and breakdown, no market signals will be forthcoming. We continue to apply irrelevant mechanical, Newtonian, reversible methodologies to natural phenomena which are governed instead by dynamic, chaotic and irreversible forces. Here is a simple illustration: In the orthodox market view, extra units of anything--let's say CO2 or HFCs--added at uniform rates gives 1+1+1+1 etc. and makes a nice straight oblique line on the graph. This process, and the line that represents it, are supposed to be able to continue forever. In natural time, however, the addition of an extra unit of greenhouse gas or ozone destroying chemicals can become at any time the straw that breaks the camel's back and forces the curve to fly off the chart. The market will never tell us when that moment has arrived. I sometimes wonder if we haven't already had our wake-up calls for ozone and global warming; if the curve isn't already flying off the chart and we just haven't realised it yet. The natural environment is subject to complex feedback loops, sharp shifts, comparatively sudden and unpredictable systemic collapse and reorganisation. A few isolated economists are beginning to listen to scientists like Per Bak who has shown how large, complex, interactive systems organise themselves to a critical state in which an unpredictable, minor event sparks a chain reaction that can lead to a catastrophe. Bak calls this state 'self-organised criticality'; the chain reaction is better known as the 'sandpile' or the 'landslide effect'. Am I being unnecessarily alarmist? Mainstream economists would definitely say yes. They do not believe in natural limits and they believe that the market can solve all problems, including ecological problems. Here, for example, is the view of Mr Larry Summers who used to be Chief Economist at the World Bank and is now Under-Secretary of the US Treasury in charge of International Affairs. Summers is best known for his leaked statement that Africa is seriously under-polluted and should import toxic wastes from elsewhere. The following quote is even more revealing: There are no ... limits to the carrying capacity of the earth that are likely to bind at any time in the foreseeable future. There isn't a risk of an apocalypse due to global warming or anything else. The idea that the world is headed over an abyss is profoundly wrong. The idea that we should put limits on growth because of some natural limit is a profound error and one that, were it ever to prove nfluential, would have staggering social costs. Summers' logic is echoed by a British economist, World Bank and OECD consultant Wilfred Beckerman in his anti-environmentalist book titled 'Small is Stupid: Blowing the whistle on the Greens'. Like many economists, Beckerman accuses ecologists of fabricating 'meldramatic disaster scenarios' and claims that the answer to environmental problems is more economic growth. The richer we become, the more funds we can devote to environmental repair and clean-up. Besides, according to Beckerman, economic growth is itself responsible for greater environmental awareness. It is 'economic growth that has allowed a shift in people's prioritites from the satisfaction of basic needs to a concern with their environment and a greater willingness to devote resources to environmental protection'. Summers and Beckerman are perfect illustrations of a worldview which sees economic life as a continual circular flow from input to output, production to consumption, firms to households; where output is seen as the result of inputs of capital and labour This system is closed. Even when raw materials are introduced into the loop as a factor of production, the system remains autonomous. In other words, economists look at economics as the total system, with everything else, including nature, subordinate to it. Now I ask you to simply look out the window. That is about all it takes to recognise that the man-made economy operates within the confines of the natural world. This is so simple and obvious that it is almost always overlooked. A different way of looking at the global economy seems to me far more realistic and sane. This vision was pioneered by Nicholas Georgescu-Roegen in the early 1970s and has since been popularised by ecological economists like Herman Daly. Unfortunately, it has yet to penetrate the calculations of economists and the projects of politicians. Here is a square, or, in three dimensions, a cube which represents the economy. It is set inside the bio-sphere. In this vision, the productive process is embedded in nature. The sphere is necessarily closed because we will never be able to increase the capacity of the biosphere by a single cubic centimetre, no matter what our present or future technology. Perhaps the easiest way to understand this approach to economics is to think of the human body. Like the economy, the body is a complex system which will decay and die if it does not constantly import high-grade energy and matter from the larger system in which it lives and if it does not export, so to speak, degraded energy and matter to the outside. When you've played a set of tennis or visited the Documenta, you can't use that energy again. It is dissipated and useless. The economy also imports high-grade energy and matter from the biosphere (this is called the biosphere's 'source' function), uses them in production and finally exports its wastes and used-up energy in the form of heat into the biosphere (this is called its 'sink' function). The biosphere can only provide and assimilate so much; its capacity both as a source and as a sink is limited. This alternative vision of economics is based on the laws of thermodynamics, on flows of matter and energy and the creation of waste and useless heat, or entropy, Once you've read Georgescu-Roegen and Daly, their arguments seem blindingly, inescapably true but it's incredibly difficult to convince the economics profession of those truths. Anyone familiar with systems analysis will confirm that the rules of a subsystem do not govern the rules of the total system. This may be why it seems so hard to get the economics profession, with a few notable and honourable exceptions, to draw the circle around the square. They would have to admit that the biosphere is the total system of which our human economy is only a part. This observation has huge practical consequences. One is that questions of scale become crucial. If the 'box' of the economy is quite small with regard to the total capacity of the sphere, as it was in the eighteenth or nineteenth century, there would be no problem. Today, however, we are producing in less than two weeks the entire global output of the year 1900. The scale of the world economy at present growth rates doubles in less than 25 years. Some biologists estimate that humans are already appropriating for their own uses roughly 40% of what they call the Net Primary Product or Net Photosynthetic Product, NPP. The NPP measures the impact of human use of food, fuel, fiber and other plant output, plus human destruction of ecosystem potential through deforestation, overfishing, desertification and the like. This human appropriation of NPP is also calculated to double every 25 years. If these figures are exact--the scientific article giving the details was published in 1986--then at present rates we shall reach 80 percent human appropriation of NPP before the year 2015 and 160 percent appropriation before 2040! Furthermore, work undertaken at the University of Vancouver in Canada suggests that the richest billion and a half people in the world are already appropriating for their exclusive use the entire biophysical output of the planet. This means that global carrying capacity is already being hugely overshot and that natural degradation will therefore increase exponentially. The Vancouver team calls this phenomenon the 'ecological footprint', a unit which measures the land area and energy output required to satisfy consumption per person according to income. Thus the world's carrying capacity is affected not just by having more people, but by having much larger people. They 'weigh' more or the earth and they take up more space because they are comparatively much richer. Even if these biologists' and environmentalists' figures are way off, they still give an idea of the ecological impossibilities we face. Humans rely on other species; we simply can't grab the entire Net Photosynthetic Product and leave nothing for other living creatures. Besides, the NPP isn't going to get any larger, it is not under the control of Bill Gates or anyone else. We are facing not just a natural impossibility but a mathematical and a logical one as well. No wonder the economics profession balks and rejects the ecological worldview: it believes that continual growth is the Holy Grail and the solution to all our problems. But as the ecological economist Kenneth Boulding reminds us, 'When something grows, it gets bigger!' Growth is not the solution but the problem. For most economists, this is heresy, too shocking even to be contemplated or discussed. One can readily understand that denial of physical and biological reality can become a way of life. Some economists try to escape the dilemma by claiming that man-made capital can substitute for natural capital, so if we invest and improve our technology enough, it doesn't really matter how much natural capital we strip from the planet. This is another specious argument. Most man-made capital is still directly dependent on underlying natural resources. For instance, it makes no difference how many sawmills you have when there are no more trees; how many trawlers and canneries when there are no more fish. As for the 'sink' functions of nature, where is the man-made capital that can save us from the loss of stratospheric ozone or from the consequences of severe climate change? What if we were to embrace the alternative logic, the unconventional vision of economists like Georgescu-Roegen, Daly and Boulding and recognise that our economy is the subsystem subject to the rules of the total system which is nature? Would this mean the end of the good life? I think not. In fact, we have everything to gain from looking at the world, the biosphere, as the total system and at the economy as the sub-system. If we accept these alternative premises and this changed vision, then the first question is how much bigger can the economy get and the second, how much bigger should it get? It clearly can't go on doubling every 25 years or so in terms of total production and distribution. This is all to the good. Much of what we call growth is nothing more than the destruction of natural capital which economists don't count as the destruction it is, but as income. If a company used up its capital and counted it as income, it wouldn't stay in business for long. Furthermore, much so-called growth is making us poorer or is vainly trying to compensate for past economic and social failures. Here is a trivial example: in the United States last year, people spent about $675 million on complex electronic gear to prevent their cars from being stolen. This figure is soon expected to top $1.3 billion. Isn't it a bit short-sighted to exclaim that an epidemic of auto-theft is great news, because it contributes to growth? For that matter, so do prison construction, reconstructive surgery, cancer treatments, repairs after terrorist attacks and best of all, major or minor wars. Economic growth once correlated quite closely with increases in overall welfare, but this is no longer true. More and more growth is occasioned by social phenomena most people would rather do without. Steps to clean up a fouled environment will rank high on the list of growth-inducing projects in the coming years. Why not simply keep it clean to begin with? Overall welfare would increase even if growth did not. We don't even know how to measure precisely what proportion of present growth is the result of trying to make up for past negligence; our national accounts do not distinguish between genuine, positive, wealth-producing growth and growth that impoverishes us. As far as I know, only the Norwegians and the Dutch are seriously trying, statistically speaking, to determine which is which. In other words, we are trying to steer our highly complex economies with extraordinarily crude tools. How might we become more sophisticated in our world-view? Mere awareness of ecological problems, even if it is widespread, will never suffice to guarantee changes in policy. Consciousness raising is no substitute for building new rapports de force, new balances of power. To bring about change we shall have to confront not just inertia but many entrenched and powerful interests which for reasons already noted will put their own short-term gains first. The stress placed by human beings on the planet can be expressed by the simple formula Impact = Consumption x Technology x Population, I= C x T x P. Even though the Southern hemisphere has the bulk of the Population, the P factor; the per capita Consumption, the C factor of 1 average Northerner outstrips that of 20 average Southerners. All three factors--C, T and P need to change. Population growth rates are already declining in most of the South faster than most demographers believed they could. The best way to make them decline even faster is to educate women and girls and give them the means to control their own fertility. As for the 'T' factor, the technology we are transferring to the South is, all too often, a disgrace. The World Bank in particular is guilty of ecocide, in partnership with the elites of the South. For example, between them, the Bank and the government of India are bringing on stream a series of new power-plants to be fired with low-grade, extremely dirty but abundant coal. When completed, it is likely that these plants will by themselves produce five to ten percent of all the greenhouse gasses in the world. If the World Bank decided to go for solar energy in India and elsewhere, it could single-handedly bring down the price of solar equipment to the point that it would be competitive with cheap Indian coal, even in narrow economic terms, without even counting the benefits to the environment and to the health of ordinary Indians. But the Bank refuses to use its financial clout and to transform its major projects into environmental assets, funding instead small showcase projects as environmental alibis. The official goal of 'development' is still to provide a middle-class American or British standard of living to large segments of Southern populations. However, if the developers do not immediately switch to clean energy and clean production, we will need five or six planets to meet their objectives and, unfortunately, good planets are hard to find. As China and India show, third world countries are most unlikely to take the clean energy, clean production road by themselves because for the moment, it is more expensive. This is the vicious circle which only public spending can break. In the North, the C factor, Consumption, is the hardest to change. I still believe we can shift to an economy embedded in the natural environment without renouncing the good life. Work here in Germany at the Wuppertal Institute, recently translated into English as Factor Four: Doubling Wealth, Halving Resource Use is full of examples of ways to maintain or improve our standard of living while weighing more lightly on the earth. I recommend this book which covers much ground I do not have time to cover today. I could give a great many specific, material recommendations but we only have a short time together here. I've asked the DOCUMENTA to put an annex to my talk on the Internet, where you may want to consult it. Let me just say in conclusion that the eco-nomos, market approach to globalisation through competition and the war of all against all can only lead to collective disaster. The opposite view of the eco-logos places cooperation between people, and between people and nature, at the center of our choices. It recognises that the future depends on this cooperation. The reductionist view, a kind of primitive so-called Darwinism, is under challenge. Human culture is not based on the 'survival of the fittest'. Man first became capable of creating culture and art through collaboration. I hope that these Hundred Days will help to make this clear and speed the victory and the reign of the eco-logos. To end on a slightly Zen note, if you are in Leipzig and you want to go to Berlin but find yourself on the road to Munich, the answer is not to go faster and faster towards Munich but to stop, turn around, and head for Berlin. Thank you. --- # distributed via nettime-l : no commercial use without permission # <nettime> is a closed moderated mailinglist for net criticism, # collaborative text filtering and cultural politics of the nets # more info: majordomo@icf.de and "info nettime" in the msg body # URL: http://www.desk.nl/~nettime/ contact: nettime-owner@icf.de